Skip to site navigation

ESRC Project on The Informal Politics of Co-Decision

Summary

This project investigated a widespread yet understudied trend in European Union (EU) politics: the shift of legislative decision-making from public inclusive to restricted secluded arenas and the resulting “informalisation” of the political process. Informalisation is particularly prominent in the EU’s co-decision procedure, where a growing proportion of legislative acts is pre-agreed informally between the two co-legislators—the European Parliament (EP) and the Council of Ministers—and is subsequently adopted at first reading. The legislative procedure is abridged or “fast-tracked” accordingly. Since first reading conclusion became possible in 1999, “early agreements” have become ever more frequent, accounting for 65% of legislation passed under co-decision in the Sixth European Parliament. This development is puzzling: introduced to make EU decision-making more inclusive, accountable and transparent, the co-decision procedure has instead increased informalisation and seclusion from the electorate and from rank-and-file parliamentarians.

Against this backdrop, the project asked three questions:

  1. What is the extent and conduct of fast-track legislation?
  2. What are the reasons for fast-track legislation?
  3. What are the consequences of fast-track legislation?

The study used a mixed-methods design, combining theory-guided empirical research (quantitative hypothesis-testing, qualitative process-tracing, single-outcome study) with normative evaluation and policy-recommendations.

The research mainly contributes to the study of EU legislative politics and to the literature on informal governance. However, given a more general trend towards informal and secluded decision-making in domestic and global politics, the findings are of interest for a wider group of scholars in Comparative Politics and International Relations. The project also addresses questions of strategic importance for the Brussels policy-community and national parliaments, and its findings can directly feed into the political debate about the benefits and democratic costs of early agreements.

Findings

What is the scale and scope of informalisation? 

Descriptive statistics on the scale and scope of early agreements between mid-1999 and mid-2009 as well as on the co-variation between decision-makers’ choice to “go informal” and key characteristics of the legislative file (legal nature, policy area, complexity, salience, policy type, duration) and the main negotiators (priorities of the Council Presidency, ideological distance between Parliament’s rapporteur and national minister, Presidency’s workload) demonstrate that early agreements are not restricted to technical, urgent or uncontested files but occur across the breadth of EU legislation, and increasingly so with time. 

• Edoardo Bressanelli, Adrienne Héritier, Christel Koop and Christine Reh. “The Informal Politics of Codecision: Introducing a New Dataset on Early Agreements in the European Union”. EUI Working Paper 2014/64.

What are the reasons for informalisation?

Descriptive statistics on the scale and scope of early agreements between mid-1999 and mid-2009 as well as on the co-variation between decision-makers’ choice to “go informal” and key characteristics of the legislative file (legal nature, policy area, complexity, salience, policy type, duration) and the main negotiators (priorities of the Council Presidency, ideological distance between Parliament’s rapporteur and national minister, Presidency’s workload) demonstrate that early agreements are not restricted to technical, urgent or uncontested files but occur across the breadth of EU legislation, and increasingly so with time. 

• Christine Reh, Adrienne Héritier, Edoardo Bressanelli and Christel Koop. “The Informal Politics of Legislation: Explaining Secluded Decision-Making in the European Union”. Comparative Political Studies 46:9 (2013), 1112-1142.

What are the political consequences of fast-track legislation?

Descriptive statistics on the scale and scope of early agreements between mid-1999 and mid-2009 as well as on the co-variation between decision-makers’ choice to “go informal” and key characteristics of the legislative file (legal nature, policy area, complexity, salience, policy type, duration) and the main negotiators (priorities of the Council Presidency, ideological distance between Parliament’s rapporteur and national minister, Presidency’s workload) demonstrate that early agreements are not restricted to technical, urgent or uncontested files but occur across the breadth of EU legislation, and increasingly so with time. 

• Adrienne Héritier and Christine Reh. “Codecision and Its Discontents: Intra-Organisational Politics and Institutional Reform in the European Parliament”. West European Politics 35:5 (2012), 1134-1157.

What are the distributional consequences of fast-track legislation?

Early agreements enhance the efficiency of EU legislation, but they are criticised for giving “relais actors” within Parliament and Council disproportionate control over the legislative agenda and negotiation. A comparison of bargaining success across readings under co-decision in a dataset of salient files does, however, show that fast-track legislation has no distributional consequences when controlling for inter-institutional conflict and file characteristics. Where co-decision is concluded early, the final legislative outcomes are not located closer to the policy positions held by the party group of the Parliament’s rapporteur or by the Council presidency.

  • Anne Rasmussen and Christine Reh. “The Consequences of Concluding Co-Decision Early: Trilogues and Intra-Institutional Bargaining Success”. Journal of European Public Policy 20:7 (2013), 1006-1023.
What are the democratic consequences of informalisation?

As a strategy to cope with the complexity of policy-making informal politics is characterised by 1) restriction, 2) seclusion, 3) pre-decision-making, and 4) informal institutions. Our normative assessment depends on the evaluative standard applied: informal politics leaves formal representation largely in tact, increases efficiency and fosters accommodation, but comes at a cost for deliberation and accountability. This cost is particularly high where an informal decision is neither preceded nor followed by public debate; balanced representation in the informal arena is not guaranteed; pre-decisions are rubberstamped; and actors’ procedural rights are curtailed.

  • Christine Reh. “Informal Politics: The Normative Challenge”. In: Thomas Christiansen and Christine Neuhold (eds.). International Handbook on Informal Governance. Cheltenham, 2012.

So far, early agreements have been criticised for their lack of transparency and accountability, their challenge to deliberation and inclusiveness, and their differential empowerment of political actors. Little attention has, however, been paid to the representation of the parliamentary principal in trilogues. Based on Jane Mansbridge’s selection model of representation, it is argued that representation with a strong ‘selection core’ and a weak ‘sanction periphery’ is best-suited for bicameral bargaining, but that a set of normative standards must be met to make the selection model democratically tenable. The current practices and institutions of codecision fall short of ‘good deliberation at initial selection’ and ‘narrative accountability’; ‘ease of maintenance and de-selection’ is approximated; and ‘transparency in rationale’ has recently been strengthened. Future reform of the European Parliament’s Rules of Procedure should, therefore, introduce two democratically crucial yet hitherto neglected measures: open deliberation about the appointment of rapporteurs, and reason-giving and justification (in addition to reporting back) by trilogue negotiators.

  • “Is Informal Politics Undemocratic? Trilogues, Early Agreements and the Selection Model of Representation”. In: Journal of European Public Policy 21:6 (2014), 822-841. 
What are the policy-implications of fast-track legislation?

The project’s findings stress the political relevance of early agreements and the need to regulate the legislative practice to preserve legitimacy. On this basis, policy-recommendations were made for the EP’s 2012 review of its 2009 rules of co-legislation. Given its role as a guarantor of EU legitimacy, Parliament was called upon to put a premium on inclusiveness and transparency and to adopt a set of rules that could maintain efficient negotiation for technical proposals, facilitate effective decision-making on urgent files, and strengthen the overall legitimacy of the legislative process.

Researchers



Partners

European University Institute (EUI)
Economic and Social Research Council (ESRC)

Related links

Research

Contact us

School of Public Policy,
The Rubin Building,
29/31 Tavistock Square,
London, WC1H 9QU.
Tel: +44 (0)20 7679 4999,
Fax: +44 (0)20 7679 4969,
Email: spp@ucl.ac.uk

Postgraduate enquiries

Tel: +44 (0)20 7679 4982/4950
Email: spp.pg@ucl.ac.uk

Register with us

Register at UCL

How to find us

Connect with us

Intranets

Cookies

Site feedback



Page last modified on 17 nov 14 11:28

Footer menu